Stocks and News
Home | Week in Review Process | Terms of Use | About UsContact Us
   Articles Go Fund Me All-Species List Hot Spots Go Fund Me
Week in Review   |  Bar Chat    |  Hot Spots    |   Dr. Bortrum    |   Wall St. History
Stock and News: Hot Spots
  Search Our Archives: 
 

 

Wall Street History

https://www.gofundme.com/s3h2w8

AddThis Feed Button

   

05/14/2004

Free Marketeer

We hear his name and his main treatise thrown around quite a
bit, but just who was Adam Smith and why is he recognized as
the father of the free market?

Adam Smith (1723-90) was born in Scotland (Kirkcaldy, Fife).
By 1751 he was named a Professor of Logic at Glasgow and later
a Professor of Moral Philosophy.

Smith, it turns out, was a classic absent-minded professor. He
became quite a sight in Edinburgh and Glasgow, where he would
walk the streets in a trance with his ‘worm-like’ gait, half-
dressed, twitching all over while heatedly debating himself.
Smith once walked straight into a tanning pit in full discourse.
He always lived with his mother, it is also said.

Adam Smith first entered the realm of economics by asking
himself the implications of human greed, and how self-interest
could work for the common good. The end result turned out to
be a 1776 book titled “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
the Wealth of Nations,” a textbook of political economy.

Historian Richard Brookhiser describes the publication of
“Wealth of Nations” in the same year as the Declaration of
Independence as “a rich and resonant coincidence as if to
signal that the United States was the twin of the free market.”

And indeed Smith himself weighed in on the political goings on
back in the colonies. In deducing that you could increase
national wealth by reducing barriers that hinder growth, Smith
argued that it wasn’t necessary to have en empire (a la the Britain
of that time) in order to prosper and he specifically pointed to the
American colonies, predicting they would become independent
and that this would not result in a loss to British trade.

So let’s examine Smith’s main precepts as laid out in “Wealth of
Nations.”

Smith was going up against the prime economic philosophy of
his era, that being ‘mercantilism.’ This was the theory that “in
order to prosper, the modern state needed to manipulate every
available legal, administrative, military, and regulatory device.”
[Norman Davies] Merchants of the time looked to the state to
provide financial, political and military protection. Mercantilism
equated to protectionism.

Adam Smith argued in “Wealth of Nations” that each person
should be “free to pursue his own interest his own way,” and that
the “wretched spirit of monopoly” made people less energetic,
while “the virtue of the marketplace” would enhance social
happiness and civic virtue.

Smith thus sought to limit the functions of government to
defense, internal security, and the provision of reasonable laws
and fair law courts by which private differences could be
adjudicated. His ideal society would be led by a leisured
aristocracy, which evolves into his proposed doctrine of Laissez-
Faire: governments should not interfere in economic affairs and
free trade increased wealth.

Smith was suspicious of businessmen, advocating that freer
markets and freer trade acted as a way of disciplining them
through competition, and this competition should exist between
many small- and medium-sized companies. [Economist Henry
Kaufman notes that Smith probably wouldn’t be pleased by the
corporate behemoths of today whose successes and failures can
send shock waves through the global economy and society.]

Adam Smith wrote that a division of labor in an unregulated
market was the key to securing higher profits and maximum
prosperity for all because it would be controlled by the invisible
hand of commerce, regulated by supply and demand.

In other words, if there was a shortage of a certain product its
price would rise, thus stimulating producers to produce more
while attracting new capital into that line of production.
Conversely, if there was an excess and more was produced than
purchased, over time capital and labor would withdraw and move
into another area where demand was stronger. [The U.S.
economy today, many would argue, is undergoing one of those
shifts seeking out the Next Big Thing.]

Smith famously wrote of the specialization of labor, with his best
known example being that of the pin factory of his time, “where
each of a dozen workers engaged in only one part of the process
of manufacture, so that together they produced far more pins than
if each worker produced whole pins; the price of pins then fell,
and more pins could be used by more people.” [Source: “A
History of the Modern World”]

The same principle applied to international trade, with some
countries producing a particular item more cheaply than others,
so that by specializing and exchanging with others you benefited
the whole.

The motivation for such production and exchange was to be the
self-interest of the participants. Selfish? No, Smith argued, just
realistic; and it was morally justified because it ultimately
produced the maximum freedom and abundance of goods.

And though a bit repetitive on my part, I want to add Henry
Kaufman’s summarization of “unfettered, rational capitalism” as
espoused by Adam Smith.

In a market-based view of the world, “the allocation of resources
is purely and simply a consequence of the interplay of market
forces. It is important to recognize that this seemingly abstract
concept actually rests on a foundation of assumptions about
human nature: that man is rational, ever striving to maximize
returns in the marketplace; and that individuals and firms that do
well will prosper, whereas those that fare poorly will suffer
losses and even fail unless they modify their behavior and
improve their efficiency.”

But Kaufman argues that the chief problem with Smith’s view
“is that no industrial economy in the world is purely laissez-faire.
Pure competition is a mental construct devised by economists to
understand and illustrate certain principles. But nowhere is it a
reality. The governments of capitalist nations everywhere
recognize that major economic and financial disruptions can
endanger the well-being of the larger society, and therefore
intervene – to a greater or lesser degree – in the operation of the
market.”

---

Finally, to digress a bit, in doing this piece I couldn’t help but
think of my political science advisor at Wake Forest University
in Winston-Salem, N.C., Dr. Steintragger. I was a miserable
student and he knew I wasn’t going to turn my act around until I
got into the real world, so when we sat down to discuss my
academic record we’d end up talking about poker and beer
instead (the drinking age was 18 then, in case you’re worried).
We got along fine, even though I know he was disappointed in
me. But sometimes I think in one way he had more fun in our
discussions than with some of his other students.

Anyway, Dr. Steintragger was a specialist in the British
philosopher Jeremy Bentham (1748-1832) and in researching
Adam Smith I came across Bentham’s name because the latter is
known for the theory of “utilitarianism”; a premise that “the
greatest happiness of the greatest number” should be the subject
of individual and government action. “Every law is an evil,”
Bentham once wrote, “for every law is an infraction of liberty.”
Bentham is also known for the famous question about any law or
government institution, “does it work?” Don’t you wish this was
asked more often of the bureaucracy that exists in Washington
today?

So Dr. Steintragger, I hope you’re up in heaven playing poker
and drinking beer. Just know one of your worst students finally
got around to appreciating Jeremy Bentham, and in doing so
furthered his appreciation for a damn good professor as well.

Sources:

Richard Brookhiser, “Alexander Hamilton”
“Chambers Dictionary of World History”
Norman Davies, “Europe: A History”
Henry Kaufman, “On Money and Markets”
John Merriman, “A History of Modern Europe”
R.R. Palmer, Joel Colton, Lloyd Kramer, “A History of the
Modern World”
Peter N. Stearns, General Editor, “The Encyclopedia of World
History”

Wall Street History will return May 21.

Brian Trumbore



AddThis Feed Button

 

-05/14/2004-      
Web Epoch NJ Web Design  |  (c) Copyright 2016 StocksandNews.com, LLC.

Wall Street History

05/14/2004

Free Marketeer

We hear his name and his main treatise thrown around quite a
bit, but just who was Adam Smith and why is he recognized as
the father of the free market?

Adam Smith (1723-90) was born in Scotland (Kirkcaldy, Fife).
By 1751 he was named a Professor of Logic at Glasgow and later
a Professor of Moral Philosophy.

Smith, it turns out, was a classic absent-minded professor. He
became quite a sight in Edinburgh and Glasgow, where he would
walk the streets in a trance with his ‘worm-like’ gait, half-
dressed, twitching all over while heatedly debating himself.
Smith once walked straight into a tanning pit in full discourse.
He always lived with his mother, it is also said.

Adam Smith first entered the realm of economics by asking
himself the implications of human greed, and how self-interest
could work for the common good. The end result turned out to
be a 1776 book titled “An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of
the Wealth of Nations,” a textbook of political economy.

Historian Richard Brookhiser describes the publication of
“Wealth of Nations” in the same year as the Declaration of
Independence as “a rich and resonant coincidence as if to
signal that the United States was the twin of the free market.”

And indeed Smith himself weighed in on the political goings on
back in the colonies. In deducing that you could increase
national wealth by reducing barriers that hinder growth, Smith
argued that it wasn’t necessary to have en empire (a la the Britain
of that time) in order to prosper and he specifically pointed to the
American colonies, predicting they would become independent
and that this would not result in a loss to British trade.

So let’s examine Smith’s main precepts as laid out in “Wealth of
Nations.”

Smith was going up against the prime economic philosophy of
his era, that being ‘mercantilism.’ This was the theory that “in
order to prosper, the modern state needed to manipulate every
available legal, administrative, military, and regulatory device.”
[Norman Davies] Merchants of the time looked to the state to
provide financial, political and military protection. Mercantilism
equated to protectionism.

Adam Smith argued in “Wealth of Nations” that each person
should be “free to pursue his own interest his own way,” and that
the “wretched spirit of monopoly” made people less energetic,
while “the virtue of the marketplace” would enhance social
happiness and civic virtue.

Smith thus sought to limit the functions of government to
defense, internal security, and the provision of reasonable laws
and fair law courts by which private differences could be
adjudicated. His ideal society would be led by a leisured
aristocracy, which evolves into his proposed doctrine of Laissez-
Faire: governments should not interfere in economic affairs and
free trade increased wealth.

Smith was suspicious of businessmen, advocating that freer
markets and freer trade acted as a way of disciplining them
through competition, and this competition should exist between
many small- and medium-sized companies. [Economist Henry
Kaufman notes that Smith probably wouldn’t be pleased by the
corporate behemoths of today whose successes and failures can
send shock waves through the global economy and society.]

Adam Smith wrote that a division of labor in an unregulated
market was the key to securing higher profits and maximum
prosperity for all because it would be controlled by the invisible
hand of commerce, regulated by supply and demand.

In other words, if there was a shortage of a certain product its
price would rise, thus stimulating producers to produce more
while attracting new capital into that line of production.
Conversely, if there was an excess and more was produced than
purchased, over time capital and labor would withdraw and move
into another area where demand was stronger. [The U.S.
economy today, many would argue, is undergoing one of those
shifts seeking out the Next Big Thing.]

Smith famously wrote of the specialization of labor, with his best
known example being that of the pin factory of his time, “where
each of a dozen workers engaged in only one part of the process
of manufacture, so that together they produced far more pins than
if each worker produced whole pins; the price of pins then fell,
and more pins could be used by more people.” [Source: “A
History of the Modern World”]

The same principle applied to international trade, with some
countries producing a particular item more cheaply than others,
so that by specializing and exchanging with others you benefited
the whole.

The motivation for such production and exchange was to be the
self-interest of the participants. Selfish? No, Smith argued, just
realistic; and it was morally justified because it ultimately
produced the maximum freedom and abundance of goods.

And though a bit repetitive on my part, I want to add Henry
Kaufman’s summarization of “unfettered, rational capitalism” as
espoused by Adam Smith.

In a market-based view of the world, “the allocation of resources
is purely and simply a consequence of the interplay of market
forces. It is important to recognize that this seemingly abstract
concept actually rests on a foundation of assumptions about
human nature: that man is rational, ever striving to maximize
returns in the marketplace; and that individuals and firms that do
well will prosper, whereas those that fare poorly will suffer
losses and even fail unless they modify their behavior and
improve their efficiency.”

But Kaufman argues that the chief problem with Smith’s view
“is that no industrial economy in the world is purely laissez-faire.
Pure competition is a mental construct devised by economists to
understand and illustrate certain principles. But nowhere is it a
reality. The governments of capitalist nations everywhere
recognize that major economic and financial disruptions can
endanger the well-being of the larger society, and therefore
intervene – to a greater or lesser degree – in the operation of the
market.”

---

Finally, to digress a bit, in doing this piece I couldn’t help but
think of my political science advisor at Wake Forest University
in Winston-Salem, N.C., Dr. Steintragger. I was a miserable
student and he knew I wasn’t going to turn my act around until I
got into the real world, so when we sat down to discuss my
academic record we’d end up talking about poker and beer
instead (the drinking age was 18 then, in case you’re worried).
We got along fine, even though I know he was disappointed in
me. But sometimes I think in one way he had more fun in our
discussions than with some of his other students.

Anyway, Dr. Steintragger was a specialist in the British
philosopher Jeremy Bentham (1748-1832) and in researching
Adam Smith I came across Bentham’s name because the latter is
known for the theory of “utilitarianism”; a premise that “the
greatest happiness of the greatest number” should be the subject
of individual and government action. “Every law is an evil,”
Bentham once wrote, “for every law is an infraction of liberty.”
Bentham is also known for the famous question about any law or
government institution, “does it work?” Don’t you wish this was
asked more often of the bureaucracy that exists in Washington
today?

So Dr. Steintragger, I hope you’re up in heaven playing poker
and drinking beer. Just know one of your worst students finally
got around to appreciating Jeremy Bentham, and in doing so
furthered his appreciation for a damn good professor as well.

Sources:

Richard Brookhiser, “Alexander Hamilton”
“Chambers Dictionary of World History”
Norman Davies, “Europe: A History”
Henry Kaufman, “On Money and Markets”
John Merriman, “A History of Modern Europe”
R.R. Palmer, Joel Colton, Lloyd Kramer, “A History of the
Modern World”
Peter N. Stearns, General Editor, “The Encyclopedia of World
History”

Wall Street History will return May 21.

Brian Trumbore